Why the numbers don’t add up by Petrino DiLeo

Dandelion Salad

by Petrino DiLeo
http://socialistworker.org
June 13, 2008

Petrino DiLeo explains why the government’s official inflation statistics seem so low compared to the bite out of your pocketbook that a trip to the grocery store takes.

TURNS OUT that those high prices you’ve been paying aren’t so high after all–at least as far as the government is concerned.

A recent post on a Business Week blog previewing the release of May’s inflation data, due out today, claimed that “core” inflation has been “surprisingly subdued” over the past three months. Economists are predicting that core inflation rose 0.2 percent from April to May and experts expect core inflation in the economy to read as 2.3 percent year-over-year–very close to the Federal Reserve Bank’s target of 2.0 percent.

This might come as a shock to anyone that’s visited the supermarket or filled a gas tank lately.

From January to April, for example, the average price of a gallon of fuel oil nationally rose from $3.34 to $3.87, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, a 16 percent gain. In the past 12 months, the rise is 52 percent.

So what gives?

The problem is that the government deals in several measures when gauging the rate of inflation. It focuses on the core rate of inflation rather than the “headline” inflation rate, which attempts to measure total inflation within an economy.

Inflation, broadly speaking, is a general increase in prices throughout an economy. There is often talk of inflation in one commodity or another. But the technical definition of inflation is a broader measure. Looked at another way, inflation means that a currency becomes devalued. When inflation takes place in the U.S., a dollar will buy you less of every kind of commodity than it did previously.

Since 2000, the Federal Reserve Bank has used the core rate as the preferred means for measuring inflation. The core rate–the full name of which is the core personal consumption expenditures price index–strips out prices of commodities that economists have deemed too “volatile” for accurate measurements, namely food and energy.

In the May issue of Harper’s, author Kevin Phillips notes that Nixon administration introduced this change in the early 1970s, when food and gas prices spiked. “Core inflation could be spotlighted when the headline number was embarrassing, as it was in 1973 and 1974,” Phillips wrote. “The economic commentator Barry Ritholtz has joked that core inflation is better called ‘inflation ex-inflation’–i.e., inflation after the inflation has been excluded.”

Once again today, food and gasoline are precisely the commodities where price increases are most severe. So despite the obvious fact that grocery bills and trips to the gas station are eating increasing chunks of workers’ paychecks, the “official” rate of inflation remains “subdued.”

– – – – – – – – – – – – – – – –

THERE ARE other metrics of inflation beside the core rate that are still reported. The Bureau of Labor Statistics releases the consumer price index (CPI) and the purchaser price index (PPI) monthly. These are supposed to measure increases in prices for particular segments of the economy. The CPI measures what consumers are paying for goods, and the PPI measures prices paid to producers by retailers.

The problem is that both the PPI and CPI are, at some level, subjective measures. The rates of inflation for both are based on weighted “baskets of goods.” The CPI, for example, is determined by measuring prices of different amounts of electricity, gas, fuel oil, white bread, ground beef, chicken, eggs, milk, apples, oranges, tomatoes, orange juice, coffee and iceberg lettuce.

By stripping out the costs of gasoline and feeding a family, the core inflation rate helps the government avoid political heat. What’s more, understating the inflation rate helps the Federal Reserve Bank to keep interest rates low. Low rates, in turn, can stimulate the economy, most recently allowing the banks’ mortgage-lending binge that led to the housing bubble.

By denying inflation is occurring, the Fed and the Bush administration can try to avoid intervening in the economy to try and stop it. The working class is left to suffer a fall in its standard of living, doling out more ever more money to buy everyday necessities.

If the level of inflation does finally force the Fed to act, it has several methods that it can try. One is to decrease the supply of money in an economy through intervening in markets for government bonds. Another is to raise interest rates to discourage borrowing and investment.

The problem with both of these strategies is that they also slow economic activity in general. By undertaking them, the Federal Reserve can end up provoking a recession. This is exactly what happened in the 1980s when then-Federal Reserve Chair Paul Volcker raised interest rates to their highest level in a generation to wipe out double-digit inflation.

Now, the sharp rise in oil prices and other goods has pressured the current Fed chair, Ben Bernanke, to state that the bank will raise interest rates if inflation keeps climbing. Yet given the slow crawl of the U.S. economy, such a move could trigger a nasty slump.

Whatever comes next, it’s already clear, as Kevin Phillips argued, that working people are having a much harder time than the official statistics show.

“The real numbers, to most economically minded Americans, would be a face full of cold water,” he wrote. “Based on the criteria in place a quarter century ago, today’s U.S. unemployment rate is somewhere between 9 percent and 12 percent; the inflation rate is as high as 7 or even 10 percent; economic growth since the recession of 2001 has been mediocre, despite a huge surge in the wealth and incomes of the superrich, and we are falling back into recession.”

Material on this Web site is licensed by SocialistWorker.org, under a Creative Commons (by-nc-nd 3.0) license. Readers are welcome to share and use articles and other materials for non-commercial purposes, as long as they are attributed to the author and SocialistWorker.org.

see

Federal Reserve

The Presidential Election and U.S. Foreign Policy

Dandelion Salad

NewAmericaFoundation

The American Strategy Program gathered four celebrated political scientists—Prof. Charles Kupchan of Georgetown University, Prof. Peter Trubowitz of the University of Texas at Austin, Prof. Daniel Deudney of Johns Hopkins University, and Prof. John Ikenberry of Princeton University—for a discussion of the future of Liberal Internationalism in American foreign policy.

Profs. Kupchan and Trubowitz spoke first, outlining the argument from their recent paper asserting the demise of Liberal Internationalism in the post- Cold War era. They defined Liberal Internationalism as the combination of a commitment to multilateral institutions backed up by a willingness to use the military in a variety of international situations.

Prof. Kupchan stated that all of the present speakers (and moderator and American Strategy Director Steve Clemons) would consider themselves Liberal Internationalists, but that their disagreement rests on the view of the current state of Liberal Internationalism, and the current American political environment.

Prof. Trubowitz then spoke, providing more details about his and Prof. Kupchan’s argument. He argued that the rise of Liberal Internationalism was contingent on a rare combination of circumstances: on the one hand, the presence of an international rival (the Soviet Union) that gave an incentive for politicians to favor centrism. On the other, a domestic scene that was becoming less regionally divided and less politically polarized. As these circumstances have changed, Liberal Internationalism has faded as a politically viable idea.

Prof. Kupchan then returned to give policy suggestions for the future that would be acceptable in this new political environment: these included engagement with adversaries, looking for others (such as the EU) to share international burdens, and to engage in flexible partnerships, rather than formal alliances, both with other countries and with members of other political parties.

Prof. Deudney then took the podium, arguing instead that Liberal Internationalism is as relevant as ever. He said that ideas similar to Liberal Internationalism have been in use since America’s founding, and have been designed both domestically and internationally to ensure security and political liberty. He then described vividly the threats facing America, stating that a large-scale attack from nuclear weapons is inevitable. In a post-September 11 world, he said, Liberal Internationalism is more important than ever to preserve our liberties at home and work with allies to contain threats to America from abroad.

Prof. Ikenberry concluded with a more hopeful message on the future of Liberal Internationalism. He contended that looking at the global system over the last few centuries, the key event is the continued rise of liberal states and open economies. This “liberal ascendancy” and its impact on the international system will remain, even if American power or influence wanes. Ikenberry described a future of more Liberal Internationalism, not less, where the only impossibility is a return to the isolationism that marked America before World War II.

Vodpod videos no longer available.

more about “The Presidential Election and U.S. Fo…“, posted with vodpod

South Koreans fearful of beef

Dandelion Salad

MegaNewsbreak

US beef exports to South Korea could be labeled with the age of the cows they came from, as a way to ease concern over the safety of the meat. The Seoul government is reeling from mass protests over a deal to resume US beef imports, but as Al Jazeera’s Step Vassen reports, South Koreans fearful of mad cow disease are increasingly turning away from beef altogether.

Continue reading